Difference between revisions of "Corporation"
(Not Directory) |
|||
(3 intermediate revisions by one other user not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{otheruses}}{{redirect|Corporate}} | {{otheruses}}{{redirect|Corporate}} | ||
{{BusinessLaw}} | {{BusinessLaw}} | ||
+ | A '''corporation''' is a legal entity (technically, a [[juristic person]]) which has a separate legal personality from its members. | ||
− | + | The defining legal rights and obligations of the corporation are: (i) the ability to sue and be sued; (ii) the ability to hold assets in its own name; (iii) the ability to hire agents; (iv) the ability to sign contracts; and (v) the ability to make [[by-laws]], which govern its internal affairs.<ref>C. A. Cooke, Corporation, Trust and Company: A Legal History, (1950).</ref> Other legal rights and obligations may be assigned to the corporation by governments or courts. These are often controversial.<ref> Phillip I. Blumberg, The Multinational Challenge to Corporation Law: The Search for a New Corporate Personality, (1993) has a very good discussion of the controversial nature of additional rights being granted to corporations.</ref> | |
− | [[ | + | [[Stewart Kyd]], the author of the first treatise on corporate law in English, defined a corporation as "a collection of many individuals united into one body, under a special denomination, having perpetual succession under an artificial form, and vested, by policy of the law, with the capacity of acting, in several respects, as an individual, particularly of taking and granting property, of contracting obligations, and of suing and being sued, of enjoying privileges and immunities in common, and of exercising a variety of political rights, more or less extensive, according to the design of its institution, or the powers conferred upon it, either at the time of its creation, or at any subsequent period of its existence."{{Fact|date=December 2007}} |
+ | |||
+ | Currently, the '''modern business corporation''' is the dominant type of corporation. In addition to its legal personality, the modern business corporation has at least three other legal characteristics: (i) transferable shares (shareholders can change without affecting its status as a legal entity), (ii) perpetual succession capacity (its possible continued existence despite shareholders' death or withdrawal), (iii) and limited liability (including, but not limited to: the shareholders' limited responsibility for corporate debt, insulation from judgments against the corporation, shareholders' amnesty from criminal actions of the corporation, and, in some jurisdictions, limited liability for corporate officers and directors from criminal acts by the corporation).<ref>C. A. Cooke, Corporation, Trust and Company: A Legal History, (1950).</ref> | ||
+ | |||
+ | The modern business corporation's prevalence often obscures the fact that for years other corporate entities existed, before the emergence of the modern business corporation, for example, church, educational and charity corporations. Investors and entrepreneurs often form [[joint stock company|joint stock companies]] and then incorporated them to facilitate conducting business; as this business entity now is prevalent, the term '''corporation''' often is used to specifically refer to such '''business corporations'''. Corporations may also be formed for local government ([[municipal corporation]]), political, religious, and charitable purposes ([[not-for-profit corporation]]), or for government programs ([[government-owned corporation]]). As a generic legal term, 'corporation' means any group of persons with a legal personality. Historically, the modern business corporation emerged from the blending of the traditional corporation with the joint-stock company. | ||
==Legal status== | ==Legal status== | ||
− | The law typically views a corporation as a ''fictional person,'' a ''legal person'', or a ''moral person'' (as opposed to a natural person) | + | The existence of a corporation requires a special legal framework and body of law that specifically grants the corporation legal personality, and typically views a corporation as a ''fictional person,'' a ''legal person'', or a ''moral person'' (as opposed to a natural person). As such, corporate statutes typically give corporations the ability to own property, sign binding contracts, pay taxes in a capacity that is separate from that of its shareholders (who are sometimes referred to as "members".) |
+ | |||
+ | The legal personality has two economic implications. First it grants creditors priority over the corporate assets upon liquidation. Second, corporate assets cannot be withdrawn by its shareholders, nor can the assets of the firm be taken by personal creditors of its shareholders. The second feature requires special legislation and a special legal framework, as it cannot be reproduced via standard contract law.<ref>Hertig, The Anatomy of Corporate Law, pg 7.</ref> | ||
− | In [[common law]] countries, | + | In [[common law]] countries, classic statement of this principle is found in ''[[Lennard's Carrying Co Ltd v Asiatic Petroleum Co Ltd]]'' [1915] |
AC 705, where Lord Haldane said: | AC 705, where Lord Haldane said: | ||
− | :''"My Lords, a corporation is an abstraction. It has no mind of its own any more than it has a body of its own; its active and directing will must consequently be sought in the person of somebody who is really the directing mind and will of the corporation, the very | + | :''"My Lords, a corporation is an abstraction. It has no mind of its own any more than it has a body of its own; its active and directing will must consequently be sought in the person of somebody who is really the directing mind and will of the corporation, the very ego and centre of the personality of the corporation."'' |
− | The most | + | The regulations most favorable to [[incorporation (business)|incorporation]] include: |
− | ; Limited | + | ; Limited liability: Unlike in a [[partnership]] or [[sole proprietorship]], shareholders of a modern business corporation have "limited" [[liability]] for the corporation's debts and obligations.<ref>A leading case in common law is ''[[Salomon v. Salomon & Co.]]'' [1897] AC 22.</ref> As a result their potential losses cannot exceed the amount which they contributed to the corporation as dues or paid for [[shares]]. Limited liability regulations enable corporations to socialize their costs for the primary benefit of shareholders. The economic rationale for this lies in the fact that it allows anonymous trading in the shares of the corporation by virtue of eliminating the corporation's creditors as a stakeholder in such a transaction. Without limited liability, a creditor would not likely allow any share to be sold to a buyer of at least equivalent creditworthiness as the seller. Limited liability further allows corporations to raise tremendously more funds for enterprises by combining funds from the owners of stock. Limited liability reduces the amount that a shareholder can lose in a company. This in turn greatly reduces the risk for potential shareholders and increases both the number of willing shareholders and the amount they are likely to invest. |
− | ; Perpetual | + | ; Perpetual lifetime: Another favorable regulation, the [[assets]] and structure of the corporation exist beyond the lifetime of any of its shareholders, bondholders, or employees. This allows for stability and accumulation of capital, which thus becomes available for investment in projects of a larger size and over a longer term than if the corporate assets remained subject to [[dissolution (law)|dissolution]] and [[liquidation|distribution]]. This feature also had great importance in the [[medieval]] period, when land donated to the Church (a corporation) would not generate the feudal fees that a lord could claim upon a landholder's death. In this regard, see [[Statute of Mortmain]]. It is important to note that the "perpetual lifetime" feature is an indication of the unbounded potential duration of the corporation's existence, and its accumulation of wealth and thus power. (In theory, a corporation can have its charter revoked at any time, putting an end to its existence as a legal entity. However, in practice, dissolution only occurs for corporations that request it or fail to meet annual filing requirements.) |
===Ownership and control=== | ===Ownership and control=== | ||
− | + | Persons and other legal entities composed of persons (such as [[Trust company|trust]]s and other corporations) can have the right to vote or share in the profit of corporations. In the case of for-profit corporations, these voters hold [[share (finance)|shares]] of stock and are thus called shareholders or stockholders. When no stockholders exist, a corporation may exist as a [[non-stock corporation]], and instead of having stockholders, the corporation has members who have the right to vote on its operations. If the non-stock corporation is not operated for profit, it is called a [[not-for-profit corporation]]. In either category, the corporation comprises a collective of individuals with a distinct legal status and with special privileges not provided to ordinary unincorporated businesses, to [[voluntary association]]s, or to groups of individuals. | |
For the purposes of the next few paragraphs, the term "members" will be used to refer to stockholders of a stock corporation and members of a non-stock corporation. | For the purposes of the next few paragraphs, the term "members" will be used to refer to stockholders of a stock corporation and members of a non-stock corporation. | ||
− | + | There are two broad classes of corporate governance forms in the world. In most of the world, control of the corporation is determined by a [[board of directors]] which is elected by the shareholders. In some jurisdictions, such as Germany, the control of the corporation is divided into two tiers with a [[supervisory board]] which elects a [[managing board]]. Germany is also unique in having a system known as [[co-determination]] in which half of the supervisory board consists of representatives of the employees. | |
+ | |||
+ | The [[CEO]], president, treasurer, and other titled officers are usually chosen by the board to manage the affairs of the corporation. | ||
− | + | In addition to the influence of shareholders, corporations can be controlled (in part) by creditors such as banks. In return for lending money to the corporation, creditors can demand a controlling interest analogous to that of a member, including one or more seats on the board of directors. In some jurisdictions, such as Germany and Japan, it is standard for banks to own shares in corporations whereas in other jurisdictions such as the United States and the United Kingdom banks are prohibited from owning shares in external corporation. | |
− | Members of a corporation are said to have a "residual interest." Should the corporation end its existence, the members are the last to receive its assets, following creditors and others with interests in the corporation. This can make investment in a corporation risky; however, | + | Members of a corporation (except for non-profit corporations) are said to have a "residual interest." Should the corporation end its existence, the members are the last to receive its assets, following creditors and others with interests in the corporation. This can make investment in a corporation risky; however, a diverse investment portfolio minimizes this risk. In addition, shareholders receive the benefit of limited liability regulations, making shareholders liable for only the amount they contributed. This only applies in the case of for-profit corporations; non-profits are not allowed to have residual benefits available to the members. |
===Formation=== | ===Formation=== | ||
− | Historically, corporations were created by special [[charter]] of governments. Today, corporations are usually registered with the state, province, or | + | Historically, corporations were created by special [[charter]] of governments. Today, corporations are usually registered with the state, province, or national government and become regulated by the laws enacted by that government. Registration is the main prerequisite to the corporation's assumption of limited liability. As part of this registration, it must in many cases be required to designate the principal address of the corporation as well as a [[registered agent]] (a person or company that is designated to receive legal service of process). As part of the registration, it may also be required to designate an [[Agent (law)|agent]] or other legal representative of the corporation depending on the filing jurisdiction. |
Generally, a corporation files [[articles of incorporation]] with the government, laying out the general nature of the corporation, the amount of stock it is authorized to issue, and the names and addresses of directors. Once the articles are approved, the corporation's directors meet to create [[bylaws]] that govern the internal functions of the corporation, such as meeting procedures and officer positions. | Generally, a corporation files [[articles of incorporation]] with the government, laying out the general nature of the corporation, the amount of stock it is authorized to issue, and the names and addresses of directors. Once the articles are approved, the corporation's directors meet to create [[bylaws]] that govern the internal functions of the corporation, such as meeting procedures and officer positions. | ||
− | The law of the jurisdiction in which a corporation operates will regulate most of its internal activities, as well as its finances. If a corporation operates outside its home state, it is often required to register with other governments as a [[foreign corporation]], and is almost always subject to laws of its host state pertaining to [[employment]], [[ | + | The law of the jurisdiction in which a corporation operates will regulate most of its internal activities, as well as its finances. If a corporation operates outside its home state, it is often required to register with other governments as a [[foreign corporation]], and is almost always subject to laws of its host state pertaining to [[employment]], [[crime]]s, [[contract]]s, [[civil action]]s, and the like. |
===Naming=== | ===Naming=== | ||
− | + | ''See [[Types of corporations]] for a full list. '' | |
− | In most countries, corporate names include the term "Corporation", or an abbreviation that denotes the corporate status of the entity. | + | Corporations generally have a distinct name. Historically, some corporations were named after their membership: for instance, "The President and Fellows of Harvard College." Nowadays, corporations in most jurisdictions have a distinct name that does not need to make reference to their membership. In Canada, this possibility is taken to its logical extreme: many smaller Canadian corporations have no names at all, merely numbers based on their [[Provincial Sales Tax]] registration number (e.g., "12345678 Ontario Limited"). |
+ | |||
+ | In most countries, corporate names include the term "Corporation", or an abbreviation that denotes the corporate status of the entity. These terms vary by jurisdiction and language. In some jurisdictions they are mandatory, and in others they are not.<ref>The [[U.S. state]] of [[California]] is an example of a jurisdiction that does not require corporations to indicate corporate status in their names, except for close corporations. The drafters of the 1977 revision of the California General Corporation Law considered the possibility of forcing all California corporations to have a name indicating corporate status, but decided against it because of the huge number of corporations that would have had to change their names, and the lack of any evidence that anyone had been harmed in California by entities whose corporate status was not immediately apparent from their names. However, the 1977 drafters were able to impose the current disclosure requirement for close corporations. See Harold Marsh, Jr., R. Roy Finkle, Larry W. Sonsini, and Ann Yvonne Walker, ''Marsh's California Corporation Law'', 4th ed., vol. 1 (New York: Aspen Publishers, ), 5-15 — 5-16.</ref> Their use puts all persons on [[constructive notice]] that they have to deal with an entity whose [[liability]] remains limited, in the sense that it does not reach back to the persons who constitute the entity; one can only collect from whatever assets the entity still controls at the time one obtains a judgment against it. | ||
Certain jurisdictions do not allow the use of the word "'''company'''" alone to denote corporate status, since the word "company" may refer to a [[partnership]] or to a [[sole proprietorship]], or even, archaically, to a group of not necessarily related people (for example, those staying in a tavern). | Certain jurisdictions do not allow the use of the word "'''company'''" alone to denote corporate status, since the word "company" may refer to a [[partnership]] or to a [[sole proprietorship]], or even, archaically, to a group of not necessarily related people (for example, those staying in a tavern). | ||
===Unresolved issues=== | ===Unresolved issues=== | ||
− | The nature of the corporation continues to evolve | + | The nature of the corporation continues to evolve through existing corporations pushing new ideas and structures, courts responding, and governments regulating in response to new situations. A question of long standing is that of diffused responsibility: for example, if the corporation is found liable for a death, then how should the blame and punishment for this be allocated across the shareholders, directors, management and staff of the corporation, and the corporation itself? See [[corporate manslaughter]] specifically, and [[corporate liability]] generally. |
− | |||
− | |||
− | + | The present law differs among jurisdictions, and is in a state of flux. Some argue that the shareholders should be ultimately responsible for such circumstances, forcing them to consider issues other than profit when investing, but the modern corporation may have many millions of small shareholders who know nothing about its business activities. In addition, traders — especially [[hedge fund]]s — may rapidly turn over their shares in corporation many times a day.<ref>See, for example, the Canadian province of Ontario's Environmental Protection Act.</ref>The issue of corporate repeat offenders (see H.Glasbeak, "Wealth by Stealth: Corporate Crime, Corporate Law, and the Perversion of Democracy" (Between the lines press: Toronto 2002) raises the question of the so-called "death penalty for corporations."<ref>[http://www.corpwatch.org/article.php?id=1810 CorpWatch : The Death Penalty for Corporations Comes of Age<!-- Bot generated title -->]</ref> | |
==Origins== | ==Origins== | ||
===Etymology=== | ===Etymology=== | ||
− | The word "corporation" derives from the | + | The word "corporation" derives from the Latin ''Corpus'' (body), representing a "body of people"; that is, a ''group of people authorized to act as an individual'' ([[Oxford English Dictionary]]). The word ''universitas'' also used to refer to a group of people but now refers specifically to a group of scholars (see [[University]]). In England the term ''corporation'' was also used for the local government body in charge of a [[borough]]. This style was replaced in most cases with the term [[City Council|council]] in Britain in 1973, and in the Republic of Ireland. The sole exception is the [[Corporation of London]] which retains the title. |
===Pre-modern corporations=== | ===Pre-modern corporations=== | ||
− | Corporations have been present in some forms as far back as | + | Corporations have been present in some forms as far back as [[Economic history of India|ancient India]] and [[ancient Rome]]. Although devoid of some of the core characteristics by which corporations are known today, they nonetheless were enterprises with a form of shareholders who invested money for a specific purpose. Such corporations in the [[Roman Empire]] were sanctioned by the state, while such corporations in the [[Maurya Empire]] were mostly private commercial entities.<ref>Vikramaditya S. Khanna (2005). [http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= ''The Economic History of the Corporate Form in Ancient India.''] [[University of Michigan]].</ref> |
− | With the collapse of the | + | With the collapse of the Roman Empire, the Roman conception of the corporation merged with other views. [[Germanic peoples|Germanic]] tribes, for example, maintained that a group entity in and of itself could have a separate identity from that of its members. |
These influences came together in the body of canon law built around the conception of the church as corporate structure in the Middle Ages. Different theories of the church as corporate body were favored by different individuals but all agreed on one key component: that the church was more than just its members and could maintain an existence perpetually, regardless of the death of any individual member. | These influences came together in the body of canon law built around the conception of the church as corporate structure in the Middle Ages. Different theories of the church as corporate body were favored by different individuals but all agreed on one key component: that the church was more than just its members and could maintain an existence perpetually, regardless of the death of any individual member. | ||
− | This, together with discussion as to the relationship between the head of a corporation (such as the Pope) and its members, contributed not only to the development of modern corporations and [[corporate theory]] but also set the stage for many ideas that would come to fruition during the enlightenment. [[Kenneth Pomeranz]], an economic historian, argues that the need to perform pseudo-governmental operations (such as the waging of | + | This, together with discussion as to the relationship between the head of a corporation (such as the Pope) and its members, contributed not only to the development of modern corporations and [[corporate theory]] but also set the stage for many ideas that would come to fruition during the enlightenment. [[Kenneth Pomeranz]], an economic historian, argues that the need to perform pseudo-governmental operations (such as the waging of war) accounts for the development of this economic structure in Europe but not in China or in the Middle East. |
The law classifies a corporation either as a [[corporation sole]] (one person) or as a [[corporation aggregate]] (any other number). | The law classifies a corporation either as a [[corporation sole]] (one person) or as a [[corporation aggregate]] (any other number). | ||
Line 66: | Line 75: | ||
===Development of modern commercial corporations=== | ===Development of modern commercial corporations=== | ||
[[Image:Stora Kopparberg 1288.jpg|thumb|250px|right|1/8 share of the [[Stora Kopparberg]] mine, dated [[June 16]] [[1288]].]] | [[Image:Stora Kopparberg 1288.jpg|thumb|250px|right|1/8 share of the [[Stora Kopparberg]] mine, dated [[June 16]] [[1288]].]] | ||
− | [[Image: | + | [[Image:Vereinigte Ostindische Compagnie bond.jpg|thumb|250px|A [[bond]] issued by the [[Dutch East India Company]], dating from 1623, for the amount of 2,400 florins]] |
− | Early corporations of the commercial sort were formed under frameworks set up by governments of | + | Early corporations of the commercial sort were formed under frameworks set up by governments of states to undertake tasks which appeared too risky or too expensive for individuals or governments to embark upon. The alleged oldest commercial corporation in the world, the [[Stora Kopparberg]] mining community in [[Falun]], [[Sweden]], obtained a [[charter]] from King [[Magnus II of Sweden|Magnus Eriksson]] in 1347. Many European nations chartered corporations to lead colonial ventures, such as the [[Dutch East India Company]] or the [[Hudson's Bay Company]], and these corporations came to play a large part in the history of [[corporate colonialism]]. |
− | In the [[United States]], government chartering began to fall out of vogue in the mid-1800s. Corporate law at the time was focused on protection of the public interest, and not on the interests of corporate shareholders. Corporate charters were closely regulated by the states. Forming a corporation usually required an act of legislature. Investors generally had to be given an equal say in corporate governance, and corporations were required to comply with the purposes expressed in their charters. Many private firms in the 19th century avoided the corporate model for these reasons ([[Andrew Carnegie]] formed his steel operation as a [[limited partnership]], and [[John D. Rockefeller]] set up [[Standard Oil]] as a trust). Eventually, state governments began to realize the greater corporate registration revenues available by providing more permissive corporate laws. [[New Jersey]] was the first state to adopt an "enabling" corporate law, with the goal of attracting more business to the state. [[Delaware]] followed, and soon became known as the most corporation-friendly state in the country after New Jersey raised taxes on the corporations | + | In the [[United States]], government chartering began to fall out of vogue in the mid-1800s. Corporate law at the time was focused on protection of the public interest, and not on the interests of corporate shareholders. Corporate charters were closely regulated by the states. Forming a corporation usually required an act of legislature. Investors generally had to be given an equal say in corporate governance, and corporations were required to comply with the purposes expressed in their charters. Many private firms in the 19th century avoided the corporate model for these reasons ([[Andrew Carnegie]] formed his steel operation as a [[limited partnership]], and [[John D. Rockefeller]] set up [[Standard Oil]] as a [[Trust (19th century)|trust]]). Eventually, state governments began to realize the greater corporate registration revenues available by providing more permissive corporate laws. [[New Jersey]] was the first state to adopt an "enabling" corporate law, with the goal of attracting more business to the state.<ref>The Law of Business Organizations[http://books.google.com/books?id=ftzqaBv7X_sC&pg=PA159&lpg=PA159&dq=%22new+jersey%22+%22first+state%22+%22business+corporation%22&source=web&ots=n5Af0liBo5&sig=A2RRh_zOyS7W3CCMK4ZyG6Scmwk]</ref> [[Delaware]] followed, and soon became known as the most corporation-friendly state in the country after New Jersey raised taxes on the corporations, driving them out. New Jersey reduced these taxes after this mistake was realized, but by then it was too late; even today, most major public corporations are set up under Delaware law. |
− | The 20th century saw a proliferation of enabling law across the world, which some argue helped to drive economic booms in many countries before and after | + | The 20th century saw a proliferation of enabling law across the world, which some argue helped to drive economic booms in many countries before and after World War I (the advantage to the overall economy of enabling laws must, however, be viewed in light of the success of Carnegie Steel and Standard Oil, the economic stimulus of the war, the flourishing of the automotive sector, and other major economic drivers). Starting in the 1980s, many countries with large state-owned corporations moved toward [[privatization]], the selling of publicly owned services and enterprises to corporations. [[Deregulation]] -- reducing the public-interest regulation of corporate activity -- often accompanied privatization as part of an ideologically [[laissez-faire]] policy. Another major postwar shift was toward development of [[Conglomerate (company)|conglomerate]]s, in which large corporations purchased smaller corporations to expand their industrial base. Japanese firms developed a horizontal conglomeration model, the [[keiretsu]], which was later duplicated in other countries as well. While corporate efficiency (and profitability) skyrocketed, small shareholder control was diminished and [[Board of directors|director]]s of corporations assumed greater control over business, contributing in part to the [[hostile takeover]] movement of the 1980s and the accounting scandals that brought down [[Enron]] and [[WorldCom]] following the turn of the century. |
− | More recent corporate developments include [[downsizing]], [[contracting-out]] or out-sourcing, [[off-shoring]] and | + | More recent corporate developments include [[downsizing]], [[contracting-out]] or out-sourcing, [[off-shoring]] and narrowing activities to [[core business]], as [[information technology]], global trade regimes, and cheap fossil fuels enable corporations to reduce and [[externalize]] labor costs, transportation costs and transaction costs, and thereby maximize profits. |
− | For a history of corporations that is “pro-corporate”, see [[John Micklethwait]] and Adrian Wooldridge, ''The Company: a Short History of a Revolutionary Idea'' (New York: Modern Library, 2003). For a history of corporations that is “critical”, see Joel Bakan, ''The Corporation. The pathological pursuit of profit and power'' (Toronto: Viking Canada, 2004). | + | For a history of corporations that is “pro-corporate”, see [[John Micklethwait]] and [[Adrian Wooldridge]], ''The Company: a Short History of a Revolutionary Idea'' (New York: Modern Library, 2003). For a history of corporations that is “critical”, see Joel Bakan, ''The Corporation. The pathological pursuit of profit and power'' (Toronto: Viking Canada, 2004). |
==Types of corporations== | ==Types of corporations== | ||
− | Most corporations are registered with the local jurisdiction as either a stock corporation or a non-stock corporation. Stock corporations | + | Most corporations are registered with the local jurisdiction as either a stock corporation or a non-stock corporation. Stock corporations sell stock to generate capital. A stock corporation is generally a for-profit corporation. A [[non-stock corporation]] does not have stockholders, but may have members who have voting rights in the corporation. |
− | Some jurisdictions (Washington, D.C., for example) separate corporations into for-profit and non-profit, as opposed to dividing into stock and non-stock. | + | Some jurisdictions ([[Washington, D.C.]], for example) separate corporations into for-profit and non-profit, as opposed to dividing into stock and non-stock. |
===For-profit and non-profit=== | ===For-profit and non-profit=== | ||
− | + | {{main|non-profit organization}} | |
− | In modern economic systems, | + | In modern economic systems, conventions of [[corporate governance]] commonly appear in a wide variety of business and [[Non-profit organization|non-profit]] activities. Though the laws governing these creatures of [[statute]] often differ, the courts often interpret provisions of the law that apply to profit-making enterprises in the same manner (or in a similar manner) when applying principles to non-profit organizations — as the underlying structures of these two types of entity often resemble each other. |
===Closely held and public=== | ===Closely held and public=== | ||
− | The institution most often referenced | + | The institution most often referenced by the word "corporation" is a '''public''' or '''publicly traded''' corporation, the shares of which are traded on a public market (e.g., the [[New York Stock Exchange]] or [[Nasdaq]]) designed specifically for the buying and selling of shares of stock of corporations by and to the general public. Most of the largest businesses in the world are publicly traded corporations. However, the majority of corporations are said to be '''closely held''', '''privately held''' or '''close corporations''', meaning that no ready market exists for the trading of shares. Many such corporations are owned and managed by a small group of businesspeople or companies, although the size of such a corporation can be as vast as the largest public corporations. |
+ | |||
+ | Closely held corporations do have some advantages over publicly traded corporations. A small, closely held company can often make company-changing decisions much more rapidly than a publicly traded company. A publicly traded company is also at the mercy of the market, having capital flow in and out based not only on what the company is doing but the market and even what the competitors are doing. Publicly traded companies also have advantages over their closely held counterparts. Publicly traded companies often have more working capital and can delegate debt throughout all shareholders. This means that people invested in a publicly traded company will each take a much smaller hit to their own capital as opposed to those involved with a closely held corporation. Publicly traded companies though suffer from this exact advantage. A closely held corporation can often voluntarily take a hit to profit with little to no repercussions (as long as it is not a sustained loss). A publicly traded company though often comes under extreme scrutiny if profit and growth are not evident to stock holders, thus stock holders may sell, further damaging the company. Often this blow is enough to make a small public company fail. | ||
+ | |||
+ | Often communities benefit from a closely held company more so than from a public company. A closely held company is far more likely to stay in a single place that has treated them well, even if going through hard times. The shareholders can incur some of the damage the company may receive from a bad year or slow period in the company profits. Workers benefit in that closely held companies often have a better relationship with workers. In larger, publicly traded companies, often when a year has gone badly the first area to feel the effects are the work force with lay offs or worker hours, wages or benefits being cut. Again, in a closely held business the shareholders can incur this profit damage rather than passing it to the workers. Closely held businesses are also often known to be more [[socially responsible]] than publicly traded companies. | ||
The affairs of publicly traded and closely held corporations are similar in many respects. The main difference in most countries is that publicly traded corporations have the burden of complying with additional securities laws, which (especially in the U.S.) may require additional periodic disclosure (with more stringent requirements), stricter corporate governance standards, and additional procedural obligations in connection with major corporate transactions (e.g. mergers) or events (e.g. elections of directors). | The affairs of publicly traded and closely held corporations are similar in many respects. The main difference in most countries is that publicly traded corporations have the burden of complying with additional securities laws, which (especially in the U.S.) may require additional periodic disclosure (with more stringent requirements), stricter corporate governance standards, and additional procedural obligations in connection with major corporate transactions (e.g. mergers) or events (e.g. elections of directors). | ||
+ | |||
+ | ===Mutual benefit corporations=== | ||
+ | |||
+ | <!-- NOTICE: the following text was copied verbatim from a (United States) state government website, and thus not protected by copyright. A citation is given. --> | ||
+ | A mutual benefit nonprofit corporation is a corporation formed in the United States solely for the benefit of its members. An example of a mutual benefit nonprofit corporation is a golf club. Individuals pay to join the club, memberships may be bought and sold, and any property owned by the club is distributed to its members if the club dissolves. The club can decide, in its corporate bylaws, how many members to have, and who can be a member. Generally, while it is a nonprofit corporation, a mutual benefit corporation is not a charity. Because it is not a charity, a mutual benefit nonprofit corporation cannot obtain 501(c)(3) status. If there is a dispute as to how a mutual benefit nonprofit corporation is being operated, it is up to the members to resolve the dispute since the corporation exists to solely serve the needs of its membership and not the general public.<ref>[http://www.sec.state.vt.us/tutor/dobiz/forms/definitions/mutben.htm Official website of the Secretary of State, for the (United States) state of Vermont]</ref> | ||
===Multinational corporations=== | ===Multinational corporations=== | ||
− | + | {{main|Multinational corporation}} | |
− | Following on the success of the corporate model at a national level, many corporations have become transnational or [[multinational corporation]]s: growing beyond national boundaries to attain sometimes remarkable positions of power and influence in the process of [[ | + | Following on the success of the corporate model at a national level, many corporations have become transnational or [[multinational corporation]]s: growing beyond national boundaries to attain sometimes remarkable positions of power and influence in the process of [[globalization|globalizing]]. |
− | The typical "transnational" or "multinational" may fit into a web of overlapping | + | The typical "transnational" or "multinational" may fit into a web of overlapping shareholders and directorships, with multiple branches and lines in different regions, many such sub-groupings comprising corporations in their own right. Growth by expansion may favor national or regional branches; growth by [[acquisition]] or [[merger]] can result in a plethora of groupings scattered around and/or spanning the globe, with structures and names which do not always make clear the structures of shareholder ownership and interaction. |
− | In the spread of corporations across multiple continents, the importance of [[corporate culture]] has grown as a unifying factor and a counterweight to local national sensibilities and cultural awareness. | + | In the spread of corporations across multiple continents, the importance of [[Organizational culture|corporate culture]] has grown as a unifying factor and a counterweight to local national sensibilities and cultural awareness. |
− | == | + | ===Australia=== |
− | + | In [[Australia]] corporations are registered and regulated by the Commonwealth Government through the [[Australian Securities and Investments Commission]]. Corporations law has been largely codified in the [[Corporations Act 2001]]. | |
− | === | + | |
− | In the [[ | + | ===Brazil=== |
+ | In [[Brazil]] there are many different types of corporations ("sociedades"), but the two most common ones commercially speaking are: (i) "sociedade limitada", identified by "Ltda." after the company's name, equivalent to the British limited company, and (ii) "sociedade anônima" or "companhia", identified by "SA" or "Companhia" in the company's name, equivalent to the British public limited company. The "Ltda." is mainly governed by the new Civil Code, enacted in 2002, and the "SA" by the Law 6.404 dated [[15 December]] [[1976]]. | ||
+ | |||
+ | ===Canada=== | ||
+ | In [[Canada]] both the federal government and the [[province]]s have corporate statutes, and thus a corporation may have a provincial or a federal charter. Many older corporations in Canada stem from [[Act of Parliament|Acts of Parliament]] passed before the introduction of general corporation law. The oldest corporation in Canada is the [[Hudson's Bay Company]], chartered in 1670. Federally recognized corporations are regulated by the [[Canada Business Corporations Act]]. | ||
+ | |||
+ | ===German-speaking countries=== | ||
+ | [[Germany]], [[Austria]], [[Switzerland]] and [[Liechtenstein]] recognize two forms of corporation: the [[Aktiengesellschaft]] (AG), analogous to public corporations in the English-speaking world, and the [[Gesellschaft mit beschränkter Haftung]] (GmbH), similar to (and an inspiration for) the modern [[limited liability company]]. | ||
− | + | ===Italy=== | |
+ | [[Italy]] recognises two forms of companies with limited liability: "S.r.l", or "Società a Responsabilità Limitata" (similar to [[Limited liability company]]) and "S.p.A" or "Società Per Azioni" (similar to American stock corporation). | ||
− | + | ===United Kingdom=== | |
+ | In the [[United Kingdom]], 'corporation' most commonly refers to a [[publicly-owned company]], of which few now remain. The [[BBC]] is the oldest and best known corporation still in existence. Others, such as the [[British Steel Corporation]], were [[privatized]] in the 1980s. | ||
− | + | In the private sector, the most common type of company in the UK is the private [[limited company]] ("Limited" or "Ltd."). Private limited companies can either be limited by shares or by guarantee. Other corporate forms include the [[public limited company]] ("PLC") and the [[unlimited company]]. | |
− | + | ===United States=== | |
+ | Several types of corporations exist in the [[United States]]. Generically, any business entity that is recognized as distinct from the people who own it (i.e., is not a sole proprietorship or a partnership) is a corporation. This generic label includes entities that are known by such legal labels as ‘association’, ‘organization’ and ‘limited liability company’, as well as corporations proper. Only a company that has been formally incorporated according to the laws of a particular state is called ‘corporation’. American corporations can be either profit-making companies or non-profit entities. Tax-exempt non-profit corporations are often called “501(c)3 corporation”, after the section of the [[Internal Revenue Code]] that addresses their tax exemption. | ||
− | + | Corporations are created by filing the requisite documents with a particular state government. The process is called “incorporation” and refers to the abstract concept of clothing the business entity with a veil of artificial person hood (of “corporating” it – ‘corpus’ being the Latin for “body”). Only certain corporations, such as banks, are chartered. The rest merely file their articles of incorporation with the state government as part of a registration process. | |
− | + | The [[government of the United States|federal government]] can only create corporate entities pursuant to relevant powers in the [[United States Constitution|U.S. Constitution]]. For example, Congress has constitutional power to regulate banking, so it has power to charter federal banks. Additionally, Congress has power to create and own corporations that serve a purpose of the federal government, such as [[Amtrak]] and the [[United States Postal Service|U.S. Postal Service]]. | |
− | + | Once incorporated, the corporation has artificial personhood everywhere it may operate, until such time as the corporation may be dissolved. A corporation that operates in one state while being incorporated in another is a “foreign corporation.” This label also applies to corporations incorporated outside of the United States. Foreign corporations must usually register with the [[United States Secretary of State]]’s office to lawfully conduct business in that state. | |
− | + | A corporation is legally a citizen of the state (or other jurisdiction) in which it is incorporated (except when circumstances direct the corporation be classified as a citizen of the state in which it has its head office, or the state in which it does the majority of its business). Corporate business law differs from state to state, and many prospective corporations choose to incorporate in a state whose laws are most favorable to its business interests. Many large corporations are incorporated in [[Delaware corporation|Delaware]], for example, without being physically located there because that state has very favorable corporate tax and disclosure laws. | |
− | + | Companies set up for [[privacy]] or asset protection often incorporate in [[Nevada]], which does not require disclosure of share ownership. Many states, particularly smaller ones, have modeled their corporate statutes after the [[Model Business Corporation Act]], one of many model sets of law prepared and published by the [[American Bar Association]]. | |
− | + | As [[juristic persons]], corporations have certain rights that attach to natural purposes. The vast majority of them attach to corporations under state law, especially the law of the state in which the company is incorporated – since the corporations very existence is predicated on the laws of that state. A few rights also attach by federal constitutional and statutory law, but they are few and far between compared to the rights of natural persons. For example, a corporation has the personal right to bring a lawsuit (as well as the capacity to be sued) and, like a natural person, a corporation can be libeled. | |
− | |||
− | + | But a corporation has no constitutional right to freely exercise its religion because religious exercise is something that only "natural" persons can do. That is, only human beings, not business entities, have the necessary faculties of belief and spirituality that enable them to possess and exercise religious beliefs. | |
− | |||
− | + | [[Harvard College]] (a component of [[Harvard University]]), formally the [[President and Fellows of Harvard College]] (also known as the Harvard Corporation), is the oldest corporation in the western hemisphere. Founded in 1636, the second of Harvard’s two governing boards was incorporated by the [[Great and General Court of Massachusetts]] in 1650. Significantly, Massachusetts itself was a corporate colony at that time – owned and operated by the Massachusetts Bay Company (until it lost its charter in 1684) - so Harvard College is a corporation created by a corporation. | |
− | [[ | ||
− | + | Many nations have modeled their own corporate laws on American business law. Corporate law in [[Saudi Arabia]], for example, follows the model of New York State corporate law. | |
− | [[ | ||
==Corporate taxation== | ==Corporate taxation== | ||
− | In many countries, including the United States and United Kingdom, corporate profits are taxed at a [[corporate tax]] rate, and dividends paid to shareholders are taxed at a separate rate. Such a system is sometimes referred to as "double taxation, | + | In many countries, including the United States and United Kingdom, corporate profits are taxed at a [[corporate tax]] rate, and dividends paid to shareholders are taxed at a separate rate. Such a system is sometimes referred to as "double taxation", because any profits distributed to shareholders will eventually be taxed twice. One solution to this (as in the case of Australia and UK tax systems) is for the recipient of the dividend to be entitled to a tax credit which addresses the fact that the profits represented by the dividend have already been taxed. The company profit being passed on is therefore effectively only taxed at the rate of tax paid by the eventual recipient of the dividend. |
== Criticisms == | == Criticisms == | ||
− | [[Adam Smith]] in the [[Wealth of Nations]] criticized the corporate form because of the separation of ownership and management. | + | <blockquote> |
+ | "It has no body to kick and no soul to damn."<ref>Attributed to [[Edward Thurlow, 1st Baron Thurlow|Lord Thurlow LC]], although it does not appear in any of his reported decisions. It has been suggested that he actually said "Corporations have neither bodies to be punished, nor souls to be condemned, they therefore do as they like."[http://www.netsoc.tcd.ie/~eof/q]</ref> | ||
+ | </blockquote> | ||
+ | |||
+ | [[Adam Smith]] in the [[Wealth of Nations]] criticized the [[joint-stock company]] corporate form because of the separation of ownership and management. | ||
<blockquote> | <blockquote> | ||
The directors of such [joint-stock] companies, however, being the managers rather of other people’s money than of their own, it cannot well be expected, that they should watch over it with the same anxious vigilance with which the partners in a private copartnery frequently watch over their own.... Negligence and profusion, therefore, must always prevail, more or less, in the management of the affairs of such a company. | The directors of such [joint-stock] companies, however, being the managers rather of other people’s money than of their own, it cannot well be expected, that they should watch over it with the same anxious vigilance with which the partners in a private copartnery frequently watch over their own.... Negligence and profusion, therefore, must always prevail, more or less, in the management of the affairs of such a company. | ||
</blockquote> | </blockquote> | ||
− | Legal Scholar and Professor of Law at the [[University of British Columbia]] [[Joel Bakan]] describes the modern corporate entity as 'an institutional psychopath' and a 'psychopathic creature.' Bakan claims that corporations, when considered as natural persons, exhibit the traits of [[antisocial personality disorder]] or [[psychopathy]]. | + | The context for Adam Smith’s term for “companies” in the [[Wealth of Nations]] was the joint-stock company. In the 18th century, the joint-stock company was a distinct entity created by the King of England as Royal Charter trading companies. These entities were awarded legal monopoly in designated regions of the world. See Wikipedia cited example of the [[British East India Company]]. |
+ | |||
+ | Furthermore the context of the quote points to the complications inherent in chartered joint-stock companies. Each company had a Courts of Governors and day-to-day duties were overseen by local managers. Governor supervision of day-to-day operations was minimal and was exacerbated by the geography of the 18th century. | ||
+ | |||
+ | The sailing time from India to England was many months and round trip routes often took a year or longer. It was during the interim time period that local managers took advantage of the time delay by plundering the local population at the expense of the interests of shareholders. Bribery and corruption were inherent in this type of corporate model as the local managers sought to avoid close supervision by the Courts of Governors, politicians, and Prime Ministers. In these circumstances, Smith did not consider joint-stock company governance to be honest.<ref>[http://adamsmithslostlegacy.com/2007/02/18th-century-chartered-joint-stock.html Adam Smith The Lost Legacy.com]</ref> | ||
+ | |||
+ | Legal Scholar and Professor of Law at the [[University of British Columbia]] [[Joel Bakan]] describes the modern corporate entity as 'an institutional psychopath' and a 'psychopathic creature.' In his documentary ''[[The Corporation]]'', Bakan claims that corporations, when considered as natural living persons, exhibit the traits of [[antisocial personality disorder]] or [[psychopathy]]. Also in the film, Robert Monks, a former [[Republican Party (United States)|Republican Party]] candidate for Senate from [[Maine]], claims that: | ||
− | + | <blockquote>"The corporation is an externalizing machine (moving its operating costs to external organizations and people), in the same way that a shark is a killing machine."<ref>Bakan, Joel (writer) [http://www.thecorporation.com/ The Corporation (2003)] (Documentary)</ref></blockquote> | |
− | <blockquote> | ||
− | |||
− | + | Noam Chomsky has criticized the legal decisions that led to the creation of the modern corporation: | |
− | Chomsky has | ||
<blockquote> | <blockquote> | ||
− | Corporations, which previously had been considered artificial entities with no rights, were accorded all the rights of persons, and far more, since they are "immortal persons, | + | Corporations, which previously had been considered artificial entities with no rights, were accorded all the rights of persons, and far more, since they are "immortal persons", and "persons" of extraordinary wealth and power. Furthermore, they were no longer bound to the specific purposes designated by State charter, but could act as they choose, with few constraints.<ref>Robert Barksky, ''Noam Chomsky and the Law'' [http://www.chomsky.info/onchomsky/1999----02.htm]</ref> |
</blockquote> | </blockquote> | ||
+ | |||
+ | Two scholars who believe the corporate form serves the general welfare, [[Frank Easterbrook]] and [[Daniel Fischel]] have made part of their case in these words: | ||
+ | |||
+ | "First, limited liability decreases the need to monitor agents. To protect themselves [in its absence], investors could monitor their agents more closely. The more risk they bear, the more they will monitor. But beyond a point extra monitoring is not worth the cost. Moreover, specialized risk bearing implies that many investors will have diversified holdings. Only a portion of their wealth will be invested in one firm. These diversified investors have neither the expertise nor the incentive to monitor the actions of more specialized agents. Limiteds liability makes diversification and passivity a more rational strategy and so potentially reduces the cost of operating the corporation." | ||
+ | |||
+ | [[The Economic Structure of Corporate Law]] [[1991]]. | ||
==Other business entities== | ==Other business entities== | ||
Almost every recognized type of organization carries out some economic activities (e.g. the [[family business|family]]). Other organizations that may carry out activities that are generally considered to be ''business'' exist under the laws of various countries. These include: | Almost every recognized type of organization carries out some economic activities (e.g. the [[family business|family]]). Other organizations that may carry out activities that are generally considered to be ''business'' exist under the laws of various countries. These include: | ||
+ | * [[Consumers' cooperative]] | ||
* [[Partnership]] | * [[Partnership]] | ||
* [[Limited partnership]] (LP) | * [[Limited partnership]] (LP) | ||
Line 169: | Line 207: | ||
* [[Sole proprietorship]] | * [[Sole proprietorship]] | ||
* [[Trust company]], [[Trust law]] | * [[Trust company]], [[Trust law]] | ||
+ | |||
+ | ==Footnotes== | ||
+ | {{reflist}} | ||
+ | |||
+ | ==References== | ||
+ | * [[Robert Sobel|Sobel, Robert]]. ''The Age of Giant Corporations: a Microeconomic History of American Business''. (1984) | ||
+ | *Klein and Coffee. ''Business Organization and Finance: Legal and Economic Principles''. Foundation. 2002. ISBN -X | ||
+ | *[[Robert Hessen|Hessen, Robert]]. ''In Defense of the Corporation''. Hoover Institute. 1979. ISBN -X | ||
+ | *Bromberg, Alan R. ''Crane and Bromberg on Partnership''. 1968. | ||
+ | *Conard, Alfred F. ''Corporations in Perspective''. 1976. | ||
+ | *Dignam, A and Lowry, J (2006) Company Law, Oxford University Press ISBN-13: 978-0-19-928936-3 | ||
+ | *John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge. ''The Company: a Short History of a Revolutionary Idea''. New York: Modern Library. 2003. | ||
+ | *Blumberg, Phillip I., ''The Multinational Challenge to Corporation Law: The Search for a New Corporate Personality'', (1993) | ||
+ | |||
+ | *John William Cadman, ''The Corporation in New Jersey: Business and Politics, '', (1949) | ||
+ | *C. A. Cooke, ''Corporation, Trust and Company: A Legal History'', (1950) | ||
+ | *John P. Davis, [http://socserv2.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/davisjohn/index.html ''Corporations''] (1904) | ||
+ | *Joseph S. Davis, [http://socserv2.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/davisjoe/index.html ''Essays in the Earlier History of American Corporations''] (1917) | ||
+ | *A.B. DuBois, ''The English Business Company after the Bubble Act, '', (1938) | ||
+ | *Edwin Merrick Dodd, ''American Business Corporations until 1860, With Special Reference to Massachusetts'', (1954) | ||
+ | *Charles Freedman, ''Joint-stock Enterprise in France, : From Privileged Company to Modern Corporation'' (1979) | ||
+ | *[[Ernst Freund]], [http://socserv2.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/freund/index.html ''The Legal Nature of the Corporation''], (1897) | ||
+ | *Frederick Hallis, ''Corporate Personality: A Study in Jurisprudence'' (1930) | ||
+ | *Bishop Hunt, ''The Development of the Business Corporation in England '' (1936) | ||
+ | *Ramesh Chandra Majumdar, [http://socserv2.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/majumdar/index.html ''Corporate Life in Ancient India''], (1920) | ||
+ | *Robert Charles Means, ''Underdevelopment and the Development of Law: Corporations and Corporation Law in Nineteenth-century Colombia'', (1980) | ||
+ | *Thomas Owen, ''The Corporation under Russian Law, : A Study in Tsarist Economic Policy'' (1991) | ||
+ | *Radhe Shyam Rungta, ''The Rise of the Business Corporation in India, 1851–1900'', (1970) | ||
+ | *W. R. Scott, [http://socserv2.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/scott/index.html ''Constitution and Finance of English, Scottish and Irish Joint-Stock Companies to 1720''] (1912) | ||
+ | *Bruce Brown, [http://www.astonisher.com/archives/corporation/corporation_intro.html ''The History of the Corporation''] (2003) | ||
+ | |||
+ | ==See also== | ||
+ | *[[Blocker corporation]] | ||
+ | *[[Bylaw]] | ||
+ | *[[Commercial law]] | ||
+ | *[[Community interest company]] | ||
+ | *[[Company (law)]] | ||
+ | *[[Conglomerate (company)]] | ||
+ | *[[Cooperative]] | ||
+ | *[[Corporate Darwinism]] | ||
+ | *[[Corporate governance]] | ||
+ | *[[Corporate haven]] | ||
+ | *[[Corporatism]] | ||
+ | *[[Delaware corporation]] | ||
+ | *[[Finance capitalism]] | ||
+ | *[[Anti-corporate activism]] | ||
+ | *[[Guild]] | ||
+ | *[[Incorporation (business)]] | ||
+ | *[[Limited liability company]] (LLC) | ||
+ | *[[Megacorporation]] (fictional) | ||
+ | *[[Organizational culture]] | ||
+ | *[[Preferred stock]] | ||
+ | *[[Public limited company]] (PLC) | ||
+ | *[[Registered Agent]] | ||
+ | *[[Shelf Corporation]] | ||
+ | *[[Stock certificate]]s | ||
+ | *''[[The Corporation]]'' A documentary criticizing the role and purpose of the corporation | ||
+ | *[[Unlimited liability corporation]] | ||
+ | |||
+ | ==External links== | ||
+ | *''[[wikibooks:US Corporate Law|US Corporate Law]]'' at Wikibooks | ||
+ | |||
+ | [[Category:Companies| ]] | ||
+ | [[Category:Business law]] | ||
+ | [[Category:Corporations law]] | ||
+ | [[Category:Legal entities]] | ||
+ | [[Category:Types of companies]] | ||
+ | |||
+ | [[br:Embregerezh]] | ||
+ | [[cs:Obchodní společnost]] | ||
+ | [[de:Körperschaft]] | ||
+ | [[et:Ettevõte]] | ||
+ | [[es:Corporación]] | ||
+ | [[eo:Entrepreno]] | ||
+ | [[fr:corporation]] | ||
+ | [[hr:Korporacija]] | ||
+ | [[hu:Vállalat]] | ||
+ | [[ko:주식회사]] | ||
+ | [[he:תאגיד]] | ||
+ | [[id:Perusahaan]] | ||
+ | [[it:Società (diritto)]] | ||
+ | [[ja:株式会社]] | ||
+ | [[lv:Uzņēmums]] | ||
+ | [[lb:Entreprise]] | ||
+ | |||
+ | [[nl:Bedrijf]] | ||
+ | [[no:Aksjeselskap]] | ||
+ | [[nn:Aksjeselskap]] | ||
+ | [[pl:Korporacja]] | ||
+ | [[pt:Corporação]] | ||
+ | [[ro:Corporaţie]] | ||
+ | [[ru:Коммерческая организация]] | ||
+ | [[simple:Corporation]] | ||
+ | [[sl:Podjetje]] | ||
+ | [[sr:Корпорација]] | ||
+ | [[tr:Şirket]] | ||
+ | [[yi:קארפארעישאן]] | ||
+ | [[zh:股份有限公司]] |
Latest revision as of 23:28, 11 February 2008
Template:OtherusesTemplate:Redirect Template:BusinessLaw A corporation is a legal entity (technically, a juristic person) which has a separate legal personality from its members.
The defining legal rights and obligations of the corporation are: (i) the ability to sue and be sued; (ii) the ability to hold assets in its own name; (iii) the ability to hire agents; (iv) the ability to sign contracts; and (v) the ability to make by-laws, which govern its internal affairs.[1] Other legal rights and obligations may be assigned to the corporation by governments or courts. These are often controversial.[2]
Stewart Kyd, the author of the first treatise on corporate law in English, defined a corporation as "a collection of many individuals united into one body, under a special denomination, having perpetual succession under an artificial form, and vested, by policy of the law, with the capacity of acting, in several respects, as an individual, particularly of taking and granting property, of contracting obligations, and of suing and being sued, of enjoying privileges and immunities in common, and of exercising a variety of political rights, more or less extensive, according to the design of its institution, or the powers conferred upon it, either at the time of its creation, or at any subsequent period of its existence."Template:Fact
Currently, the modern business corporation is the dominant type of corporation. In addition to its legal personality, the modern business corporation has at least three other legal characteristics: (i) transferable shares (shareholders can change without affecting its status as a legal entity), (ii) perpetual succession capacity (its possible continued existence despite shareholders' death or withdrawal), (iii) and limited liability (including, but not limited to: the shareholders' limited responsibility for corporate debt, insulation from judgments against the corporation, shareholders' amnesty from criminal actions of the corporation, and, in some jurisdictions, limited liability for corporate officers and directors from criminal acts by the corporation).[3]
The modern business corporation's prevalence often obscures the fact that for years other corporate entities existed, before the emergence of the modern business corporation, for example, church, educational and charity corporations. Investors and entrepreneurs often form joint stock companies and then incorporated them to facilitate conducting business; as this business entity now is prevalent, the term corporation often is used to specifically refer to such business corporations. Corporations may also be formed for local government (municipal corporation), political, religious, and charitable purposes (not-for-profit corporation), or for government programs (government-owned corporation). As a generic legal term, 'corporation' means any group of persons with a legal personality. Historically, the modern business corporation emerged from the blending of the traditional corporation with the joint-stock company.
Legal status
The existence of a corporation requires a special legal framework and body of law that specifically grants the corporation legal personality, and typically views a corporation as a fictional person, a legal person, or a moral person (as opposed to a natural person). As such, corporate statutes typically give corporations the ability to own property, sign binding contracts, pay taxes in a capacity that is separate from that of its shareholders (who are sometimes referred to as "members".)
The legal personality has two economic implications. First it grants creditors priority over the corporate assets upon liquidation. Second, corporate assets cannot be withdrawn by its shareholders, nor can the assets of the firm be taken by personal creditors of its shareholders. The second feature requires special legislation and a special legal framework, as it cannot be reproduced via standard contract law.[4]
In common law countries, classic statement of this principle is found in Lennard's Carrying Co Ltd v Asiatic Petroleum Co Ltd [1915] AC 705, where Lord Haldane said:
- "My Lords, a corporation is an abstraction. It has no mind of its own any more than it has a body of its own; its active and directing will must consequently be sought in the person of somebody who is really the directing mind and will of the corporation, the very ego and centre of the personality of the corporation."
The regulations most favorable to incorporation include:
- Limited liability
- Unlike in a partnership or sole proprietorship, shareholders of a modern business corporation have "limited" liability for the corporation's debts and obligations.[5] As a result their potential losses cannot exceed the amount which they contributed to the corporation as dues or paid for shares. Limited liability regulations enable corporations to socialize their costs for the primary benefit of shareholders. The economic rationale for this lies in the fact that it allows anonymous trading in the shares of the corporation by virtue of eliminating the corporation's creditors as a stakeholder in such a transaction. Without limited liability, a creditor would not likely allow any share to be sold to a buyer of at least equivalent creditworthiness as the seller. Limited liability further allows corporations to raise tremendously more funds for enterprises by combining funds from the owners of stock. Limited liability reduces the amount that a shareholder can lose in a company. This in turn greatly reduces the risk for potential shareholders and increases both the number of willing shareholders and the amount they are likely to invest.
- Perpetual lifetime
- Another favorable regulation, the assets and structure of the corporation exist beyond the lifetime of any of its shareholders, bondholders, or employees. This allows for stability and accumulation of capital, which thus becomes available for investment in projects of a larger size and over a longer term than if the corporate assets remained subject to dissolution and distribution. This feature also had great importance in the medieval period, when land donated to the Church (a corporation) would not generate the feudal fees that a lord could claim upon a landholder's death. In this regard, see Statute of Mortmain. It is important to note that the "perpetual lifetime" feature is an indication of the unbounded potential duration of the corporation's existence, and its accumulation of wealth and thus power. (In theory, a corporation can have its charter revoked at any time, putting an end to its existence as a legal entity. However, in practice, dissolution only occurs for corporations that request it or fail to meet annual filing requirements.)
Ownership and control
Persons and other legal entities composed of persons (such as trusts and other corporations) can have the right to vote or share in the profit of corporations. In the case of for-profit corporations, these voters hold shares of stock and are thus called shareholders or stockholders. When no stockholders exist, a corporation may exist as a non-stock corporation, and instead of having stockholders, the corporation has members who have the right to vote on its operations. If the non-stock corporation is not operated for profit, it is called a not-for-profit corporation. In either category, the corporation comprises a collective of individuals with a distinct legal status and with special privileges not provided to ordinary unincorporated businesses, to voluntary associations, or to groups of individuals.
For the purposes of the next few paragraphs, the term "members" will be used to refer to stockholders of a stock corporation and members of a non-stock corporation.
There are two broad classes of corporate governance forms in the world. In most of the world, control of the corporation is determined by a board of directors which is elected by the shareholders. In some jurisdictions, such as Germany, the control of the corporation is divided into two tiers with a supervisory board which elects a managing board. Germany is also unique in having a system known as co-determination in which half of the supervisory board consists of representatives of the employees.
The CEO, president, treasurer, and other titled officers are usually chosen by the board to manage the affairs of the corporation.
In addition to the influence of shareholders, corporations can be controlled (in part) by creditors such as banks. In return for lending money to the corporation, creditors can demand a controlling interest analogous to that of a member, including one or more seats on the board of directors. In some jurisdictions, such as Germany and Japan, it is standard for banks to own shares in corporations whereas in other jurisdictions such as the United States and the United Kingdom banks are prohibited from owning shares in external corporation.
Members of a corporation (except for non-profit corporations) are said to have a "residual interest." Should the corporation end its existence, the members are the last to receive its assets, following creditors and others with interests in the corporation. This can make investment in a corporation risky; however, a diverse investment portfolio minimizes this risk. In addition, shareholders receive the benefit of limited liability regulations, making shareholders liable for only the amount they contributed. This only applies in the case of for-profit corporations; non-profits are not allowed to have residual benefits available to the members.
Formation
Historically, corporations were created by special charter of governments. Today, corporations are usually registered with the state, province, or national government and become regulated by the laws enacted by that government. Registration is the main prerequisite to the corporation's assumption of limited liability. As part of this registration, it must in many cases be required to designate the principal address of the corporation as well as a registered agent (a person or company that is designated to receive legal service of process). As part of the registration, it may also be required to designate an agent or other legal representative of the corporation depending on the filing jurisdiction.
Generally, a corporation files articles of incorporation with the government, laying out the general nature of the corporation, the amount of stock it is authorized to issue, and the names and addresses of directors. Once the articles are approved, the corporation's directors meet to create bylaws that govern the internal functions of the corporation, such as meeting procedures and officer positions.
The law of the jurisdiction in which a corporation operates will regulate most of its internal activities, as well as its finances. If a corporation operates outside its home state, it is often required to register with other governments as a foreign corporation, and is almost always subject to laws of its host state pertaining to employment, crimes, contracts, civil actions, and the like.
Naming
See Types of corporations for a full list.
Corporations generally have a distinct name. Historically, some corporations were named after their membership: for instance, "The President and Fellows of Harvard College." Nowadays, corporations in most jurisdictions have a distinct name that does not need to make reference to their membership. In Canada, this possibility is taken to its logical extreme: many smaller Canadian corporations have no names at all, merely numbers based on their Provincial Sales Tax registration number (e.g., "12345678 Ontario Limited").
In most countries, corporate names include the term "Corporation", or an abbreviation that denotes the corporate status of the entity. These terms vary by jurisdiction and language. In some jurisdictions they are mandatory, and in others they are not.[6] Their use puts all persons on constructive notice that they have to deal with an entity whose liability remains limited, in the sense that it does not reach back to the persons who constitute the entity; one can only collect from whatever assets the entity still controls at the time one obtains a judgment against it.
Certain jurisdictions do not allow the use of the word "company" alone to denote corporate status, since the word "company" may refer to a partnership or to a sole proprietorship, or even, archaically, to a group of not necessarily related people (for example, those staying in a tavern).
Unresolved issues
The nature of the corporation continues to evolve through existing corporations pushing new ideas and structures, courts responding, and governments regulating in response to new situations. A question of long standing is that of diffused responsibility: for example, if the corporation is found liable for a death, then how should the blame and punishment for this be allocated across the shareholders, directors, management and staff of the corporation, and the corporation itself? See corporate manslaughter specifically, and corporate liability generally.
The present law differs among jurisdictions, and is in a state of flux. Some argue that the shareholders should be ultimately responsible for such circumstances, forcing them to consider issues other than profit when investing, but the modern corporation may have many millions of small shareholders who know nothing about its business activities. In addition, traders — especially hedge funds — may rapidly turn over their shares in corporation many times a day.[7]The issue of corporate repeat offenders (see H.Glasbeak, "Wealth by Stealth: Corporate Crime, Corporate Law, and the Perversion of Democracy" (Between the lines press: Toronto 2002) raises the question of the so-called "death penalty for corporations."[8]
Origins
Etymology
The word "corporation" derives from the Latin Corpus (body), representing a "body of people"; that is, a group of people authorized to act as an individual (Oxford English Dictionary). The word universitas also used to refer to a group of people but now refers specifically to a group of scholars (see University). In England the term corporation was also used for the local government body in charge of a borough. This style was replaced in most cases with the term council in Britain in 1973, and in the Republic of Ireland. The sole exception is the Corporation of London which retains the title.
Pre-modern corporations
Corporations have been present in some forms as far back as ancient India and ancient Rome. Although devoid of some of the core characteristics by which corporations are known today, they nonetheless were enterprises with a form of shareholders who invested money for a specific purpose. Such corporations in the Roman Empire were sanctioned by the state, while such corporations in the Maurya Empire were mostly private commercial entities.[9]
With the collapse of the Roman Empire, the Roman conception of the corporation merged with other views. Germanic tribes, for example, maintained that a group entity in and of itself could have a separate identity from that of its members.
These influences came together in the body of canon law built around the conception of the church as corporate structure in the Middle Ages. Different theories of the church as corporate body were favored by different individuals but all agreed on one key component: that the church was more than just its members and could maintain an existence perpetually, regardless of the death of any individual member.
This, together with discussion as to the relationship between the head of a corporation (such as the Pope) and its members, contributed not only to the development of modern corporations and corporate theory but also set the stage for many ideas that would come to fruition during the enlightenment. Kenneth Pomeranz, an economic historian, argues that the need to perform pseudo-governmental operations (such as the waging of war) accounts for the development of this economic structure in Europe but not in China or in the Middle East.
The law classifies a corporation either as a corporation sole (one person) or as a corporation aggregate (any other number).
Development of modern commercial corporations
Early corporations of the commercial sort were formed under frameworks set up by governments of states to undertake tasks which appeared too risky or too expensive for individuals or governments to embark upon. The alleged oldest commercial corporation in the world, the Stora Kopparberg mining community in Falun, Sweden, obtained a charter from King Magnus Eriksson in 1347. Many European nations chartered corporations to lead colonial ventures, such as the Dutch East India Company or the Hudson's Bay Company, and these corporations came to play a large part in the history of corporate colonialism.
In the United States, government chartering began to fall out of vogue in the mid-1800s. Corporate law at the time was focused on protection of the public interest, and not on the interests of corporate shareholders. Corporate charters were closely regulated by the states. Forming a corporation usually required an act of legislature. Investors generally had to be given an equal say in corporate governance, and corporations were required to comply with the purposes expressed in their charters. Many private firms in the 19th century avoided the corporate model for these reasons (Andrew Carnegie formed his steel operation as a limited partnership, and John D. Rockefeller set up Standard Oil as a trust). Eventually, state governments began to realize the greater corporate registration revenues available by providing more permissive corporate laws. New Jersey was the first state to adopt an "enabling" corporate law, with the goal of attracting more business to the state.[10] Delaware followed, and soon became known as the most corporation-friendly state in the country after New Jersey raised taxes on the corporations, driving them out. New Jersey reduced these taxes after this mistake was realized, but by then it was too late; even today, most major public corporations are set up under Delaware law.
The 20th century saw a proliferation of enabling law across the world, which some argue helped to drive economic booms in many countries before and after World War I (the advantage to the overall economy of enabling laws must, however, be viewed in light of the success of Carnegie Steel and Standard Oil, the economic stimulus of the war, the flourishing of the automotive sector, and other major economic drivers). Starting in the 1980s, many countries with large state-owned corporations moved toward privatization, the selling of publicly owned services and enterprises to corporations. Deregulation -- reducing the public-interest regulation of corporate activity -- often accompanied privatization as part of an ideologically laissez-faire policy. Another major postwar shift was toward development of conglomerates, in which large corporations purchased smaller corporations to expand their industrial base. Japanese firms developed a horizontal conglomeration model, the keiretsu, which was later duplicated in other countries as well. While corporate efficiency (and profitability) skyrocketed, small shareholder control was diminished and directors of corporations assumed greater control over business, contributing in part to the hostile takeover movement of the 1980s and the accounting scandals that brought down Enron and WorldCom following the turn of the century.
More recent corporate developments include downsizing, contracting-out or out-sourcing, off-shoring and narrowing activities to core business, as information technology, global trade regimes, and cheap fossil fuels enable corporations to reduce and externalize labor costs, transportation costs and transaction costs, and thereby maximize profits.
For a history of corporations that is “pro-corporate”, see John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge, The Company: a Short History of a Revolutionary Idea (New York: Modern Library, 2003). For a history of corporations that is “critical”, see Joel Bakan, The Corporation. The pathological pursuit of profit and power (Toronto: Viking Canada, 2004).
Types of corporations
Most corporations are registered with the local jurisdiction as either a stock corporation or a non-stock corporation. Stock corporations sell stock to generate capital. A stock corporation is generally a for-profit corporation. A non-stock corporation does not have stockholders, but may have members who have voting rights in the corporation.
Some jurisdictions (Washington, D.C., for example) separate corporations into for-profit and non-profit, as opposed to dividing into stock and non-stock.
For-profit and non-profit
In modern economic systems, conventions of corporate governance commonly appear in a wide variety of business and non-profit activities. Though the laws governing these creatures of statute often differ, the courts often interpret provisions of the law that apply to profit-making enterprises in the same manner (or in a similar manner) when applying principles to non-profit organizations — as the underlying structures of these two types of entity often resemble each other.
Closely held and public
The institution most often referenced by the word "corporation" is a public or publicly traded corporation, the shares of which are traded on a public market (e.g., the New York Stock Exchange or Nasdaq) designed specifically for the buying and selling of shares of stock of corporations by and to the general public. Most of the largest businesses in the world are publicly traded corporations. However, the majority of corporations are said to be closely held, privately held or close corporations, meaning that no ready market exists for the trading of shares. Many such corporations are owned and managed by a small group of businesspeople or companies, although the size of such a corporation can be as vast as the largest public corporations.
Closely held corporations do have some advantages over publicly traded corporations. A small, closely held company can often make company-changing decisions much more rapidly than a publicly traded company. A publicly traded company is also at the mercy of the market, having capital flow in and out based not only on what the company is doing but the market and even what the competitors are doing. Publicly traded companies also have advantages over their closely held counterparts. Publicly traded companies often have more working capital and can delegate debt throughout all shareholders. This means that people invested in a publicly traded company will each take a much smaller hit to their own capital as opposed to those involved with a closely held corporation. Publicly traded companies though suffer from this exact advantage. A closely held corporation can often voluntarily take a hit to profit with little to no repercussions (as long as it is not a sustained loss). A publicly traded company though often comes under extreme scrutiny if profit and growth are not evident to stock holders, thus stock holders may sell, further damaging the company. Often this blow is enough to make a small public company fail.
Often communities benefit from a closely held company more so than from a public company. A closely held company is far more likely to stay in a single place that has treated them well, even if going through hard times. The shareholders can incur some of the damage the company may receive from a bad year or slow period in the company profits. Workers benefit in that closely held companies often have a better relationship with workers. In larger, publicly traded companies, often when a year has gone badly the first area to feel the effects are the work force with lay offs or worker hours, wages or benefits being cut. Again, in a closely held business the shareholders can incur this profit damage rather than passing it to the workers. Closely held businesses are also often known to be more socially responsible than publicly traded companies.
The affairs of publicly traded and closely held corporations are similar in many respects. The main difference in most countries is that publicly traded corporations have the burden of complying with additional securities laws, which (especially in the U.S.) may require additional periodic disclosure (with more stringent requirements), stricter corporate governance standards, and additional procedural obligations in connection with major corporate transactions (e.g. mergers) or events (e.g. elections of directors).
Mutual benefit corporations
A mutual benefit nonprofit corporation is a corporation formed in the United States solely for the benefit of its members. An example of a mutual benefit nonprofit corporation is a golf club. Individuals pay to join the club, memberships may be bought and sold, and any property owned by the club is distributed to its members if the club dissolves. The club can decide, in its corporate bylaws, how many members to have, and who can be a member. Generally, while it is a nonprofit corporation, a mutual benefit corporation is not a charity. Because it is not a charity, a mutual benefit nonprofit corporation cannot obtain 501(c)(3) status. If there is a dispute as to how a mutual benefit nonprofit corporation is being operated, it is up to the members to resolve the dispute since the corporation exists to solely serve the needs of its membership and not the general public.[11]
Multinational corporations
Following on the success of the corporate model at a national level, many corporations have become transnational or multinational corporations: growing beyond national boundaries to attain sometimes remarkable positions of power and influence in the process of globalizing.
The typical "transnational" or "multinational" may fit into a web of overlapping shareholders and directorships, with multiple branches and lines in different regions, many such sub-groupings comprising corporations in their own right. Growth by expansion may favor national or regional branches; growth by acquisition or merger can result in a plethora of groupings scattered around and/or spanning the globe, with structures and names which do not always make clear the structures of shareholder ownership and interaction.
In the spread of corporations across multiple continents, the importance of corporate culture has grown as a unifying factor and a counterweight to local national sensibilities and cultural awareness.
Australia
In Australia corporations are registered and regulated by the Commonwealth Government through the Australian Securities and Investments Commission. Corporations law has been largely codified in the Corporations Act 2001.
Brazil
In Brazil there are many different types of corporations ("sociedades"), but the two most common ones commercially speaking are: (i) "sociedade limitada", identified by "Ltda." after the company's name, equivalent to the British limited company, and (ii) "sociedade anônima" or "companhia", identified by "SA" or "Companhia" in the company's name, equivalent to the British public limited company. The "Ltda." is mainly governed by the new Civil Code, enacted in 2002, and the "SA" by the Law 6.404 dated 15 December 1976.
Canada
In Canada both the federal government and the provinces have corporate statutes, and thus a corporation may have a provincial or a federal charter. Many older corporations in Canada stem from Acts of Parliament passed before the introduction of general corporation law. The oldest corporation in Canada is the Hudson's Bay Company, chartered in 1670. Federally recognized corporations are regulated by the Canada Business Corporations Act.
German-speaking countries
Germany, Austria, Switzerland and Liechtenstein recognize two forms of corporation: the Aktiengesellschaft (AG), analogous to public corporations in the English-speaking world, and the Gesellschaft mit beschränkter Haftung (GmbH), similar to (and an inspiration for) the modern limited liability company.
Italy
Italy recognises two forms of companies with limited liability: "S.r.l", or "Società a Responsabilità Limitata" (similar to Limited liability company) and "S.p.A" or "Società Per Azioni" (similar to American stock corporation).
United Kingdom
In the United Kingdom, 'corporation' most commonly refers to a publicly-owned company, of which few now remain. The BBC is the oldest and best known corporation still in existence. Others, such as the British Steel Corporation, were privatized in the 1980s.
In the private sector, the most common type of company in the UK is the private limited company ("Limited" or "Ltd."). Private limited companies can either be limited by shares or by guarantee. Other corporate forms include the public limited company ("PLC") and the unlimited company.
United States
Several types of corporations exist in the United States. Generically, any business entity that is recognized as distinct from the people who own it (i.e., is not a sole proprietorship or a partnership) is a corporation. This generic label includes entities that are known by such legal labels as ‘association’, ‘organization’ and ‘limited liability company’, as well as corporations proper. Only a company that has been formally incorporated according to the laws of a particular state is called ‘corporation’. American corporations can be either profit-making companies or non-profit entities. Tax-exempt non-profit corporations are often called “501(c)3 corporation”, after the section of the Internal Revenue Code that addresses their tax exemption.
Corporations are created by filing the requisite documents with a particular state government. The process is called “incorporation” and refers to the abstract concept of clothing the business entity with a veil of artificial person hood (of “corporating” it – ‘corpus’ being the Latin for “body”). Only certain corporations, such as banks, are chartered. The rest merely file their articles of incorporation with the state government as part of a registration process.
The federal government can only create corporate entities pursuant to relevant powers in the U.S. Constitution. For example, Congress has constitutional power to regulate banking, so it has power to charter federal banks. Additionally, Congress has power to create and own corporations that serve a purpose of the federal government, such as Amtrak and the U.S. Postal Service.
Once incorporated, the corporation has artificial personhood everywhere it may operate, until such time as the corporation may be dissolved. A corporation that operates in one state while being incorporated in another is a “foreign corporation.” This label also applies to corporations incorporated outside of the United States. Foreign corporations must usually register with the United States Secretary of State’s office to lawfully conduct business in that state.
A corporation is legally a citizen of the state (or other jurisdiction) in which it is incorporated (except when circumstances direct the corporation be classified as a citizen of the state in which it has its head office, or the state in which it does the majority of its business). Corporate business law differs from state to state, and many prospective corporations choose to incorporate in a state whose laws are most favorable to its business interests. Many large corporations are incorporated in Delaware, for example, without being physically located there because that state has very favorable corporate tax and disclosure laws.
Companies set up for privacy or asset protection often incorporate in Nevada, which does not require disclosure of share ownership. Many states, particularly smaller ones, have modeled their corporate statutes after the Model Business Corporation Act, one of many model sets of law prepared and published by the American Bar Association.
As juristic persons, corporations have certain rights that attach to natural purposes. The vast majority of them attach to corporations under state law, especially the law of the state in which the company is incorporated – since the corporations very existence is predicated on the laws of that state. A few rights also attach by federal constitutional and statutory law, but they are few and far between compared to the rights of natural persons. For example, a corporation has the personal right to bring a lawsuit (as well as the capacity to be sued) and, like a natural person, a corporation can be libeled.
But a corporation has no constitutional right to freely exercise its religion because religious exercise is something that only "natural" persons can do. That is, only human beings, not business entities, have the necessary faculties of belief and spirituality that enable them to possess and exercise religious beliefs.
Harvard College (a component of Harvard University), formally the President and Fellows of Harvard College (also known as the Harvard Corporation), is the oldest corporation in the western hemisphere. Founded in 1636, the second of Harvard’s two governing boards was incorporated by the Great and General Court of Massachusetts in 1650. Significantly, Massachusetts itself was a corporate colony at that time – owned and operated by the Massachusetts Bay Company (until it lost its charter in 1684) - so Harvard College is a corporation created by a corporation.
Many nations have modeled their own corporate laws on American business law. Corporate law in Saudi Arabia, for example, follows the model of New York State corporate law.
Corporate taxation
In many countries, including the United States and United Kingdom, corporate profits are taxed at a corporate tax rate, and dividends paid to shareholders are taxed at a separate rate. Such a system is sometimes referred to as "double taxation", because any profits distributed to shareholders will eventually be taxed twice. One solution to this (as in the case of Australia and UK tax systems) is for the recipient of the dividend to be entitled to a tax credit which addresses the fact that the profits represented by the dividend have already been taxed. The company profit being passed on is therefore effectively only taxed at the rate of tax paid by the eventual recipient of the dividend.
Criticisms
"It has no body to kick and no soul to damn."[12]
Adam Smith in the Wealth of Nations criticized the joint-stock company corporate form because of the separation of ownership and management.
The directors of such [joint-stock] companies, however, being the managers rather of other people’s money than of their own, it cannot well be expected, that they should watch over it with the same anxious vigilance with which the partners in a private copartnery frequently watch over their own.... Negligence and profusion, therefore, must always prevail, more or less, in the management of the affairs of such a company.
The context for Adam Smith’s term for “companies” in the Wealth of Nations was the joint-stock company. In the 18th century, the joint-stock company was a distinct entity created by the King of England as Royal Charter trading companies. These entities were awarded legal monopoly in designated regions of the world. See Wikipedia cited example of the British East India Company.
Furthermore the context of the quote points to the complications inherent in chartered joint-stock companies. Each company had a Courts of Governors and day-to-day duties were overseen by local managers. Governor supervision of day-to-day operations was minimal and was exacerbated by the geography of the 18th century.
The sailing time from India to England was many months and round trip routes often took a year or longer. It was during the interim time period that local managers took advantage of the time delay by plundering the local population at the expense of the interests of shareholders. Bribery and corruption were inherent in this type of corporate model as the local managers sought to avoid close supervision by the Courts of Governors, politicians, and Prime Ministers. In these circumstances, Smith did not consider joint-stock company governance to be honest.[13]
Legal Scholar and Professor of Law at the University of British Columbia Joel Bakan describes the modern corporate entity as 'an institutional psychopath' and a 'psychopathic creature.' In his documentary The Corporation, Bakan claims that corporations, when considered as natural living persons, exhibit the traits of antisocial personality disorder or psychopathy. Also in the film, Robert Monks, a former Republican Party candidate for Senate from Maine, claims that:
"The corporation is an externalizing machine (moving its operating costs to external organizations and people), in the same way that a shark is a killing machine."[14]
Noam Chomsky has criticized the legal decisions that led to the creation of the modern corporation:
Corporations, which previously had been considered artificial entities with no rights, were accorded all the rights of persons, and far more, since they are "immortal persons", and "persons" of extraordinary wealth and power. Furthermore, they were no longer bound to the specific purposes designated by State charter, but could act as they choose, with few constraints.[15]
Two scholars who believe the corporate form serves the general welfare, Frank Easterbrook and Daniel Fischel have made part of their case in these words:
"First, limited liability decreases the need to monitor agents. To protect themselves [in its absence], investors could monitor their agents more closely. The more risk they bear, the more they will monitor. But beyond a point extra monitoring is not worth the cost. Moreover, specialized risk bearing implies that many investors will have diversified holdings. Only a portion of their wealth will be invested in one firm. These diversified investors have neither the expertise nor the incentive to monitor the actions of more specialized agents. Limiteds liability makes diversification and passivity a more rational strategy and so potentially reduces the cost of operating the corporation."
The Economic Structure of Corporate Law 1991.
Other business entities
Almost every recognized type of organization carries out some economic activities (e.g. the family). Other organizations that may carry out activities that are generally considered to be business exist under the laws of various countries. These include:
- Consumers' cooperative
- Partnership
- Limited partnership (LP)
- Limited liability partnership (LLP)
- Limited liability limited partnership (LLLP)
- Limited liability company (LLC)
- Limited company (Ltd.)
- Not-for-profit corporation
- Sole proprietorship
- Trust company, Trust law
Footnotes
- ^ C. A. Cooke, Corporation, Trust and Company: A Legal History, (1950).
- ^ Phillip I. Blumberg, The Multinational Challenge to Corporation Law: The Search for a New Corporate Personality, (1993) has a very good discussion of the controversial nature of additional rights being granted to corporations.
- ^ C. A. Cooke, Corporation, Trust and Company: A Legal History, (1950).
- ^ Hertig, The Anatomy of Corporate Law, pg 7.
- ^ A leading case in common law is Salomon v. Salomon & Co. [1897] AC 22.
- ^ The U.S. state of California is an example of a jurisdiction that does not require corporations to indicate corporate status in their names, except for close corporations. The drafters of the 1977 revision of the California General Corporation Law considered the possibility of forcing all California corporations to have a name indicating corporate status, but decided against it because of the huge number of corporations that would have had to change their names, and the lack of any evidence that anyone had been harmed in California by entities whose corporate status was not immediately apparent from their names. However, the 1977 drafters were able to impose the current disclosure requirement for close corporations. See Harold Marsh, Jr., R. Roy Finkle, Larry W. Sonsini, and Ann Yvonne Walker, Marsh's California Corporation Law, 4th ed., vol. 1 (New York: Aspen Publishers, ), 5-15 — 5-16.
- ^ See, for example, the Canadian province of Ontario's Environmental Protection Act.
- ^ CorpWatch : The Death Penalty for Corporations Comes of Age
- ^ Vikramaditya S. Khanna (2005). The Economic History of the Corporate Form in Ancient India. University of Michigan.
- ^ The Law of Business Organizations[1]
- ^ Official website of the Secretary of State, for the (United States) state of Vermont
- ^ Attributed to Lord Thurlow LC, although it does not appear in any of his reported decisions. It has been suggested that he actually said "Corporations have neither bodies to be punished, nor souls to be condemned, they therefore do as they like."[2]
- ^ Adam Smith The Lost Legacy.com
- ^ Bakan, Joel (writer) The Corporation (2003) (Documentary)
- ^ Robert Barksky, Noam Chomsky and the Law [3]
References
- Sobel, Robert. The Age of Giant Corporations: a Microeconomic History of American Business. (1984)
- Klein and Coffee. Business Organization and Finance: Legal and Economic Principles. Foundation. 2002. ISBN -X
- Hessen, Robert. In Defense of the Corporation. Hoover Institute. 1979. ISBN -X
- Bromberg, Alan R. Crane and Bromberg on Partnership. 1968.
- Conard, Alfred F. Corporations in Perspective. 1976.
- Dignam, A and Lowry, J (2006) Company Law, Oxford University Press ISBN-13: 978-0-19-928936-3
- John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge. The Company: a Short History of a Revolutionary Idea. New York: Modern Library. 2003.
- Blumberg, Phillip I., The Multinational Challenge to Corporation Law: The Search for a New Corporate Personality, (1993)
- John William Cadman, The Corporation in New Jersey: Business and Politics, , (1949)
- C. A. Cooke, Corporation, Trust and Company: A Legal History, (1950)
- John P. Davis, Corporations (1904)
- Joseph S. Davis, Essays in the Earlier History of American Corporations (1917)
- A.B. DuBois, The English Business Company after the Bubble Act, , (1938)
- Edwin Merrick Dodd, American Business Corporations until 1860, With Special Reference to Massachusetts, (1954)
- Charles Freedman, Joint-stock Enterprise in France, : From Privileged Company to Modern Corporation (1979)
- Ernst Freund, The Legal Nature of the Corporation, (1897)
- Frederick Hallis, Corporate Personality: A Study in Jurisprudence (1930)
- Bishop Hunt, The Development of the Business Corporation in England (1936)
- Ramesh Chandra Majumdar, Corporate Life in Ancient India, (1920)
- Robert Charles Means, Underdevelopment and the Development of Law: Corporations and Corporation Law in Nineteenth-century Colombia, (1980)
- Thomas Owen, The Corporation under Russian Law, : A Study in Tsarist Economic Policy (1991)
- Radhe Shyam Rungta, The Rise of the Business Corporation in India, 1851–1900, (1970)
- W. R. Scott, Constitution and Finance of English, Scottish and Irish Joint-Stock Companies to 1720 (1912)
- Bruce Brown, The History of the Corporation (2003)
See also
- Blocker corporation
- Bylaw
- Commercial law
- Community interest company
- Company (law)
- Conglomerate (company)
- Cooperative
- Corporate Darwinism
- Corporate governance
- Corporate haven
- Corporatism
- Delaware corporation
- Finance capitalism
- Anti-corporate activism
- Guild
- Incorporation (business)
- Limited liability company (LLC)
- Megacorporation (fictional)
- Organizational culture
- Preferred stock
- Public limited company (PLC)
- Registered Agent
- Shelf Corporation
- Stock certificates
- The Corporation A documentary criticizing the role and purpose of the corporation
- Unlimited liability corporation
External links
- US Corporate Law at Wikibooks
br:Embregerezh cs:Obchodní společnost de:Körperschaft et:Ettevõte es:Corporación eo:Entrepreno fr:corporation hr:Korporacija hu:Vállalat ko:주식회사 he:תאגיד id:Perusahaan it:Società (diritto) ja:株式会社 lv:Uzņēmums lb:Entreprise
nl:Bedrijf no:Aksjeselskap nn:Aksjeselskap pl:Korporacja pt:Corporação ro:Corporaţie ru:Коммерческая организация simple:Corporation sl:Podjetje sr:Корпорација tr:Şirket yi:קארפארעישאן zh:股份有限公司